Digitalisation’s Marginalising Impact on India’s Unorganised Sector

Digitalisation’s Marginalising Impact on India’s Unorganised Sector
Image Credit:

Flickr Link

Digitalisation and formalisation are projected by the Government as a solution to the Indian economy’s problems. However, digitalisation has further damaged the unorganised sector without formalising it. Demand has been shifting from the unorganised to the organised sector. Given that the organised sector is more capital intensive than the unorganised sector, this demand shift has resulted in decrease in employment generation, greater inequality and shortage of demand, which have led to the economy slowing down. However, since the size of the unorganised sector is not independently estimated, it is invisiblised in the data.

Arun Kumar is a retired professor of economics, Jawaharlal Nehru University.

1. Introduction

Controversies surround India’s growth performance, especially since 2015. Officially, it is now claimed that the economy is the fastest growing large economy in the world and that only 11.3 per cent suffer ‘multidimensional poverty’ (Niti Aayog 2024). Yet, the government is giving 5 kg. of grains per month per person free to 81 crore (810 million) citizens, or 58 per cent of the population, since it believes they are unable to buy enough food. Is this not an admission that growth has not resolved the issue of poverty in India? Persistence of poverty is linked to a high level of unemployment. So, if growth is robust, why is the unemployment level high?

Could it be that the official growth and poverty data are incorrect? Data from various sources suggest that there is growing income and wealth disparity in India (Oxfam, 2023). The implication is that whatever growth is taking place is narrowly concentrated in the hands of a small per cent of the population. This is characterised as K-shaped growth, especially after the pandemic.

While inequality has existed for long, it is getting aggravated because India is following a top-down development paradigm with elite capture of policies. Soon after Independence was attained, this was moderated by the national leadership’s understanding that citizens are not responsible for their basic problems, and they cannot resolve them on their own. So these problems had to be collectively resolved via active State intervention in their favour. These mitigating policies were jettisoned in 1991 with the introduction of the New Economic Policies (NEP), and that has further aggravated inequalities (Kumar, 2013).

Since 2016, inequalities have further deteriorated, due to demonetisation, the structurally faulty Goods and Services Tax (GST), and the non-banking financial corporations (NBFC) crisis. The Government pushed policies such as demonetisation and GST in the name of formalisation and digitalisation of the economy. The lockdown in 2020 and the growth of e-commerce have worsened the situation. This article analyses these policies and their impact on the economy.

2. Unorganised Sector is Very Large – Difficulty in Estimation

The economy consists of the unorganised and the organised sectors. As per the available data (GoI, 2017a), the former employs 94 per cent of the workforce and produces 45 per cent of the output. Such a large unorganised sector does not exist in any other major economy. The differences between the two sectors are in use of technology, scale of operation, wages, access to bank credit, marketing, etc..

The unorganised sector units are so numerous that they cannot be measured every year. Periodic surveys (every five years) are carried out to collect these data, which are used to estimate the contribution of this sector to the GDP. After 2015, no survey of the unorganised sector units was carried out. From 2016 onwards, this sector has been adversely impacted by the shocks to the economy, invalidating the use of the 2015 data to estimate its performance and its contribution to the GDP. GoI (2023) shows that the share of the micro, small and medium enterprises (MSME) sector in GDP has declined from 30.5 per cent to 29.2 per cent between 2019-20 and 2021-22.

Kumar (2017) and Kumar (2019) have argued that for much of the unorganised sector, independent data are not available for estimating the sector’s contribution to GDP. For most of its sub-sectors, organised sector data are used as a proxy (see GOI, 2017b). Kumar (2020) has argued that the High Frequency Indicators (HFI) used to estimate the quarterly output represent the organised sector and not the unorganised sectors. Thus, the methodology used creates an upward bias in the contribution of the unorganised sector to GDP. Both these points have now been mentioned in a Reserve Bank of India (RBI) publication (Bhowmick, et.al. 2022). They say,

… as most of the HFIs belong to the organised sector. Therefore, information pertaining to the unorganised sector a segment contributing almost half to the overall economy remains untracked due to non-availability of robust data. …. the research agenda regarding the measurement, estimation and other issues pertaining to the informal economy remains largely unexplored…

GoI (2007), analysing the unorganised sector in the early 2000s, painted a grim picture of marginalisation of this sector in the economy, stating,

…the unorganized workers consisting of about 92% of the total workforce of 457 million (as of 2004-05). For most of them, conditions of work are utterly deplorable and livelihood options extremely few. Such a sordid picture coexists uneasily with a shining India that has successfully confronted the challenge of globalization …

… a buoyancy in the economy did lead to a sense of euphoria by the turn of the last century. However a majority of the people, who did not have even Rs.20 a day for consumption were not touched by this euphoria.

What this Report said in 2007 rings true again when the Government is claiming that the economy is booming while in reality, the unorganised sector is languishing.

3. Place of the Unorganised Sector in the Economy

The unorganised sector is also referred to as ‘informal’ and ‘unregistered’. These terms refer to units that are not registered in the Government’s records. Bhalla (2009) presented the definitional and methodological issues involved. The organised (also known as ‘formal’) sector units also employ temporary/contract workers who do not have job security, written contracts and access to social security. So, the term ‘unorganised’ refers to both labour that does not have formal rights, and the unregistered production units.

The existence of a large unorganised sector in India is the result of the adoption of the trickle-down approach to development, which marginalises the technologically backward sectors. The advanced sectors, being capital-intensive, absorb most of the investment, but offer few additional jobs. The backward sectors get a small share of investment, while most workers have no choice but to work in it. This situation got further aggravated post-1991 with the advent of the New Economic Policies (NEP) based on the idea of ‘marketisation’ (Williamson, 1989 called it the Washington Consensus). This change in the policy regime further strengthened the organised sector at the expense of the unorganised sector (See Kumar, 2013).

In each broad sector, there is an unorganised sector component, which varies from sector to sector. Agriculture is almost entirely in the unorganised sector. The public sector is entirely in the organised sector. Every other sector has both components. For instance, there are hotels and restaurants, airlines and big manufacturing companies in the organised sector, while dhabas, rickshaw pullers and micro units belong to the unorganised sector.

The organised and unorganised sectors are differentiated by technology. The former use more advanced technology and pay significantly higher wages than the latter. Most of the investment in the economy goes into the organised sector which is a) much more capital intensive and b) has a much bigger scale of operation than the unorganised sector. The high capital intensity leads to low employment generation in the organised sector. So most of the workers have to work in the unorganised sector. The latter has lower productivity, and also, because the workers are unorganised, they get a lower wage than in the organised sector (for similar work).

It should be noted in this context that even a rise in wage rates does not automatically indicate improved bargaining power of workers or rising employment levels. Wage rates may rise as mechanisation in agriculture and automation in industry replace a large number of unskilled workers with a smaller number of skilled workers/employees. In that case wages may rise despite unemployment rising, as is the case at present. Further, the extent of overtime and use of contract labour in industry are not reflected in the data, so we do not get a real picture of the hourly wage rates. In short, a seeming rise in wage rates can even go hand in hand with rising poverty.

4. Shrinking of the Unorganised Sector

Kumar (2020) has argued that the share of the unorganised sector has been shrinking since 2016-17 due to demonetisation and other developments. Kumar (2023a) gives an idea of this decline in 2022-23. Using data on aggregate output per worker, productivity in the non-agriculture unorganised sector is 0.63 times average productivity, while in the organised sector it is 9.17 times. That is, the organised sector produces 14.56 times more output per worker. So a shift in demand from the unorganised to the organised sector leads to an increase in productivity per worker, but higher unemployment/under-employment.

A shift of production from the unorganised to the organised sector does raise productivity. But it also results in an increase in under-employment and disguised unemployment, with close to zero productivity. So, the average productivity in the economy hardly increases. A corollary of these trends is that, the higher the growth rate of the organised sector, the worse the brewing unemployment crisis for workers.

Elsewhere, we have argued that under certain assumptions, the decline in the unorganised sector could be between 9.3 per cent and 5.6 per cent. (See Kumar (2023a) for an elaboration of this.) The official GDP growth rate of 7.2 per cent would then be incorrect, and actual GDP growth would lie between 2.5 per cent and 3.5 per cent. In that case, the Indian economy would not be the fastest growing large economy in the world.

Again under the above assumptions, the GDP contribution of the unorganised sector, instead of growing at 6.5 per cent (the official growth rate), would be declining at upwards of 5.6 per cent a year. Thus, on an average, post 2016, its output would be less by at least 12 per cent compared to what it could have been. So, over the seven years since 2016, the loss of output of this sector would be about Rs 84 lakh crore. (Kumar (2023a))

5. Government Pushing for the Digitalisation of Economy

The Government is pushing for the digitalisation of the economy in various ways: for example, Aadhaar, direct benefit transfer (DBT), banking, Goods and Services Tax (GST), Central Bank Digital Currency (CBDC), etc. It argues that these steps will a) lead to reduction in the black economy and increased tax collections, and b) bring the economy under its control via regulation.

However, the unorganised sector cannot be formalised through such methods, given its small scale of operations. While officially it may open bank accounts and use digital payment platforms for its transactions, these measures will not turn unorganised/informal units into the organised/formal sector. The vast majority of those working in this sector have incomes way below the taxable limit. Kumar (2023d) points out that in 2020-21, only 0.68 per cent of the population were effective income tax payers. Further, 0.016 per cent declared an income above Rs.1 crore, and their share of the taxable income was 38.6 per cent. Clearly, even most of the organised sector were not effective tax payers.

There are 30 crore (300 million) unorganised sector workers registered on the e-shram portal, and 94 per cent declare an income of below Rs 10,000 per month, or Rs 1,20,000 per annum, which is 16 per cent of the current level at which tax has to be paid. Only a few owners of unorganised businesses (say, dhabas and shop owners), and very few workers, would be in the tax net.

So, an increase in direct tax collections indicates the growth of the organised sector, and not of the economy as a whole, as the Government claims. Further, since demand is shifting to the organised sector, leading to an increase in its share of the economy, it cannot be concluded that the unorganised sector is becoming organised or formalised, and that tax collection is rising as a result.

The shift in demand from the unorganised sector is akin to its being colonised. During colonial rule, the coloniser captured the markets of the colonised nations. In India, capitalist growth is occurring at the expense of pre-capitalist formations in agriculture and the small producers.

Since the formal and organised sector is dominated by large corporations, and many of them are multinational corporations (MNCs) or with substantial investment by the MNCs and foreign portfolio investors (FPI), control of the economy is slipping into the hands of international finance capital. Since the operations of MNCs are more digitised, greater digitalisation of the economy will favour them.

Implications of Digitalisation for ‘Welfare Rights’.

Digitalisation is leaving behind many of the marginalised, who do not have access to the internet or devices such as computers and smart phones, and/or have low financial literacy. At times, even if they own devices, the connectivity is poor, so they cannot access the net. This is the internet divide. So those with limited access to internet not only cannot benefit from digitalisation, but may suffer due to inability to access services.

The digitalised systems are also not foolproof. Many kinds of errors are encountered. For example, mismatch of fingerprints or iris scans may occur during authentication. Many elderly persons have had difficulty in getting their fingerprints registered, due to age-related factors. Many workers doing heavy manual work find that their fingerprints get disfigured, as a result of which they cannot authenticate the transaction. At times, the software malfunctions, and authentication is denied. Further, due to fraud, fake accounts are created, resulting in problems for genuine persons. Scamsters are also stealing and misusing the identities of people, leading to hesitancy among people.

Due to these reasons, ‘welfare rights’ are being denied to some poor people covered by various schemes – for example, direct benefit transfers for cooking gas subsidy, payments to farmers, health benefits, ration, etc. In brief, digitalisation is a double disadvantage to many of the poor. First, it marginalises them, and second, they are often unable to avail of their legal rights.

6. Flawed Methodology to Estimate Unorganised Sector

Kumar (2023c) analyses the ‘Methodology of Compiling Quarterly GDP Estimates’ presented in GoI (2017b). Three noteworthy aspects of the method to calculate GDP from the supposedly more accurate ‘production side’ are as follows:

1. “The production approach used for compiling the QGVA [Quarterly Gross Value Added] estimates is broadly based on the benchmark-indicator method.”

2. “In this method, for each of the industry-groups, estimates of GVA [Gross Value Added] are compiled ….”

3. “In general terms, quarterly estimates of Gross Value Added (GVA) are extrapolations of annual series of GVA.”

To put it simply, in a specific year, data are directly collected about the output in the organised sector and the unorganised sector, and the relationship between the two is benchmarked. In subsequent years, data regarding the unorganised data are not directly collected; rather, organised sector output data, which are available at more frequent intervals, are used to estimate the output of the unorganised sector, on the basis of the earlier observed relationship. This method continues till a fresh survey of the unorganised sector takes places, which is usually done at five-year intervals, though at present there is a longer gap.

Thus for the quarterly estimates of GDP, based on the production approach, current data are mostly not available. So ‘benchmark indicators’ from an earlier reference year are used. The last survey of unincorporated enterprises was carried out in 2015-16 (GoI, 2017a). So a dated reference year, that does not capture the current reality, is being used.

Further, the methodology states that current figures are obtained by ‘extrapolations’ of the annual series of GVA. But, if the previous year figures are incorrect, how can their extrapolation be correct? Especially when demonetisation, introduction of GST, and the Covid lockdown administered shocks to the economy that caused disruptions (see sub-section below).

a. Shocks Undermine the Method

The methodology outlined above relies on a smoothly functioning economy. But it will not apply when there are big unexpected changes, called ‘shocks’, such as demonetisation or the sudden lockdown. Shocks have the following impact:

i) The basic parameters of the economy change, such as the ratio of the unorganised to the organised sector, or the size of the agricultural output.

ii) Hence the validity of the ‘benchmark-indicators’ comes into question.

iii) Extrapolation from a normal year to the next one that has experienced a shock would not be correct. Nor would the extrapolation from the year of shock to the next one.

The Indian economy has suffered several shocks since 2016. Demonetisation in 2016 (Kumar, 2017), the introduction of the structurally faulty GST in 2017 (Kumar, 2019), the non-banking financial corporations (NBFC) crisis in 2018, and finally the sudden lockdown in 2020 (Kumar, 2020). Each of them impacted the unorganised sector far more than it did the organised sector, thereby changing the ratio between the two and invalidating some of the ‘benchmark indicators’. Subsequently, units in the unorganised sector either did not recover at all or did so very slowly. So, even after the economy recovers, the indicators remain incorrect.

b. Shocks and Digitalisation

Demonetisation was carried out on the ground that the black economy needed to be checked (Kumar, 2017). Very quickly, it was realized that this policy objective would not be achieved, since the basic premise underlying demonetisation was incorrect. So the goalpost was shifted to making the economy ‘cashless’. It was assumed that people would be forced to give up use of cash and would shift to the digital mode and banking channels, which would leave a trail that the authorities could track.

Not only were the initial objectives of demonetisation not achieved, but the currency in circulation has shot up in spite of the rapid rise in digital transactions. As pointed out in Kumar (2017), the lasting impact has been the decline of the unorganised sector.

In July 2017, the structurally faulty GST was introduced (See Kumar, 2019). GST is calculated as a value added tax (VAT), which requires details of inputs and output. It can only work with computerisation. So it was expected to give a strong push to digitisation. All accounts of businesses were expected to become available for scrutiny by the tax authorities, thereby curbing the black economy. But, for the small and the micro sector, computerisation of accounts is too costly, given their small scale of operations. That is why producers with a turnover of less than Rs 50 lakh are exempted from GST, and if the turnover is up to Rs 1.5 crore, they are under the Composition Scheme.

In both these cases, they are not eligible to claim Input Tax Credit (ITC), and firms purchasing from such units too cannot claim ITC on those purchases. This puts the unorganised sector units at a disadvantage vis-a-vis the organised sector. (For example, let us take the case of a small unit that supplies inputs to a large manufacturer at Rs 95, and a large supplier that supplies them at Rs 100. However, only the large supplier is able to provide ITC to the large manufacturer. In that case, the effective price of the supplies from the large supplier will be lower, and therefore the large manufacturer will purchase only from the large supplier.) As a result, unorganised sector units have lost market share. A shift in demand away from the unorganised sector is reported in industries such as fast-moving consumer goods (FMCG), leather goods, luggage, and pressure cookers, and in the services sector, such as retail trade. (Kumar 2022b)

The organised sector continues to generate black incomes despite GST because of the complexity of the law and the existence of loopholes. The result has been much litigation and hundreds of changes in the laws. Fake companies to claim fictitious ITC, mispricing of produce, manipulations in e-way bills and so on are being routinely discovered. The Government revealed in the Rajya Sabha that cases of GST evasion detected had steadily risen from Rs 41,000 crore in 2019-20 to Rs 1.51 lakh crore in April-October 2023, but the rate of recovery had fallen from 45 per cent to 12 per cent (Rajya Sabha Unstarred Question no. 225, December 5, 2023).

So, while GST has forced computerisation, black income generation continues.

The sudden lockdown reduced mobility and forced people to use more of digital transactions. E-commerce, electronic payments, etc., have increased, further marginalising the unorganised sector. The government used this crisis to push its agenda of digitisation and marginalisation of workers and the farmers. The introduction of the three farm laws and implementation of the labour code are examples of this agenda.

BOX ITEM:

The Real Toll of GST on the Unorganised Sector

Two recent studies bring out the impact of the Goods and Services Tax (GST) on small enterprises.

Heavy burden of compliance costs, extremely regressive

A study by two researchers from the Madras School of Economics (MSE), S. Vishnuhadevi and D. Hima Bindu,[1] focuses on compliance costs for small firms registered under GST in Tamil Nadu. It divides compliance costs into internal costs (the value of the time spent on GST-related work, and overhead costs such as computers, stationery, travel, telephone, etc.) and external costs (payments made for work by outside professionals and agents). It finds that even firms which, due to their small turnover, were either exempt from GST, or could avail of the concessional ‘Composition Scheme’, nevertheless registered under GST.[2] They were, in a sense, “forced to take GST registration to make transactions with the medium and large businesses”, without which the medium and large businesses could not receive input tax credit (ITC).

The study found that the pattern of GST compliance costs was extremely regressive, i.e., the smaller the firm, the larger the share of its turnover devoted to GST compliance costs. This share (GST compliance costs/turnover) for the smallest firms, with turnover of Rs 40 lakh or less, was 72 times the share for firms with a turnover over Rs 25 crore. Moreover, the smaller the unit, the larger the number of hours devoted by the owner of the unit to GST compliance costs.

Using the results of the findings of their study, the authors also estimate aggregate GST compliance costs for all firms in Tamil Nadu. They find that 65 per cent of aggregate compliance costs are incurred by businesses with a turnover of less than Rs 40 lakh, and 90 per cent by businesses with a turnover of less than Rs 5 crore. On the other hand, businesses with a turnover of over Rs 500 crore accounted for just 1.6 per cent of the compliance cost.

Impact of GST on small enterprises

A very significant study[3] by Sangeeta Ghosh of Institute for Studies in Industrial Development (ISID) brings out the overall impact of GST on small enterprises. Her findings are based on a survey of 157 firms in Delhi, Mumbai and Surat, in chemicals, elastics, grey cloth, hardboard, hosiery, job work in textiles, latex thread, leather, machinery, metal parts, and textile retail. Over 80 per cent were into manufacturing or job work; 76 per cent transacted exclusively with other businesses, while another 16 per cent transacted with both businesses and consumers.

Ghosh divides her sample into three categories, according to the size of turnover. Category 1 were below the threshold, so exempted from registration under GST; Category 2 could opt for the Composition Scheme, at a lower tax rate; and Category 3 were to mandatorily register under the GST. Similarly to the MSE study, she finds that small enterprises were compelled to register, presumably because their customers were businesses registered under GST (70 per cent of Category 1 firms in her sample registered under GST, and less than 9 per cent of Category 2 firms opted for the Composition Scheme). Of the firms in the sample which were not earlier paying any taxes, over 82 per cent had now registered under GST. At the same time, since small firms earlier did much of their business with unregistered firms who would not be willing to pay GST, long-standing buyer-supplier linkages got disrupted.

The process of digitisation itself took a heavy toll on small firms, who were already struggling with lack of demand. The GST system works through a self-policing mechanism heavily dependent on information technology.[4] Ghosh writes:

Compliance costs and associated paperwork was the second-most pervasive problem (after lack of demand) facing small businesses under the GST. Four-fifths of the businesses surveyed found compliance to be a challenge. Many, filing taxes for the first time, were unaccustomed to the elaborate and complex bookkeeping. The GST necessitated a familiarity with information and communication technology and software that was beyond the capability of many small businesses. Many took recourse to hiring part-time or full-time chartered accountants to manage their books, even as their profits and incomes dwindled. Space for such bookkeeping and maintaining a computer in a small factory premise was a challenge too.

The forced modes of formal bookkeeping and filing of taxes, in which each and every transaction needed to be recorded, was an overarching task for small businesses. Digitalising these transactions meant a massive amount of labour for these enterprises, hitherto unaccustomed to such practices. It restricted their capacity to function….

While small firms are often paid by their customers after a delay, say 45 days, GST payments must be made every month. This results in blocking the working capital of small firms. As related firms too faced stress under GST, payment delays mounted from the norm of 45 days, to 75-90 days.

The overall impact of GST on small firms was severe. Of the firms surveyed, more than 50 per cent reported that, after the implementation of GST, their turnover fell by 10-30 per cent; another 36 per cent of firms reported that their turnover fell by more than 30 per cent. It was the smallest firms that experienced the most severe effects.

How did small firms cope with GST-induced stress? Of the firms surveyed, more than 50 per cent retrenched workers after the introduction of GST (in powerlooms and leather units, 100 per cent of the firms did so). The average employment per unit surveyed fell from 20 to 16.6. Average employment per powerloom unit in Surat fell from 40 to 28 workers. Firms now relied more on family labour: The number of ‘own account enterprises’ (firms without a single hired worker) rose from 7 per cent to 18 per cent. These observations, notes Ghosh, are borne out by the official Periodic Labour Force Survey for 2017-18.

While the Government claims that GST is ‘formalising’ small enterprises, this does not mean that workers in these enterprises now enjoy the rights of formal workers. Ghosh could find no evidence of formalisation of labour practices after the implementation of GST, such as paid leaves, enrolment in Provident Fund or Employees’ State Insurance Scheme, and the like.

— RUPE


  1. S. Vishnuhadevi and D. Hima Bindu, “Compliance Costs of GST for Small Enterprises in Tamil Nadu”, Working Paper 229/2022, Centre for Public Finance, Madras School of Economics, August 2022.
  2. GST taxpayers whose turnover is below a certain threshold – at present Rs 1.5 crore – can avoid complicated filings and simply pay GST every quarter at a fixed percentage of their turnover; the rate is concessional, ranging between 1 and 6 per cent.
  3. Sangeeta Ghosh, “Formalising the Informal through GST: Evidence from a Survey of MSMEs”, Review of Development and Change, 2022.
  4. The ‘Reverse Charge Mechanism’, whereby the tax is paid by the recipient of goods or services, not the manufacturer; and a system of invoice matching online.

7. Unorganised Sector Invisiblised in Data and Policy

The unorganised sector is a residual sector. If a worker does not find work in the market then she/he has to resort to self-employment to sustain self and family. For instance, workers may do headload work or pull a rickshaw. Indigenous people may collect a little bit of the forest produce and sell it at the local market or in the nearby city.

The unorganised sector is large and amorphous and beyond Government control/regulation. The Government seeks to change this through formalisation, that is, it wants that these producers be registered, use banking channels and pay taxes. But the scale of operation in this sector is tiny. The 73rd Round of the National Sample Survey found that there were over 63 million unincorporated enterprises in India in 2015-16, employing 111 million workers in manufacturing, trading and other services, with an average employment of 1.7 and Rs 2.3 lakh of fixed assets per enterprise. More than 84 per cent of these enterprises, employing 62 per cent of the workforce, were ‘own account enterprises’ (OAEs), without a single hired worker. The remaining enterprises, with at least one hired worker, are termed ‘establishments’. Establishments hired an average of only 4.2 workers per enterprise, and had a Gross Value Added of only Rs 6.4 lakh per enterprise per year. (GoI, 2017a) Hence most units in this sector have difficulty in registering, digitising or using banking. Even when they do get registered, these producers will remain small and will not turn into the organised sector – they only get damaged by having to comply with the burdensome processes.

Kumar (2023d) points out that India’s tax base is small. Till 2022-23, income tax was to be paid at incomes 4.5 times the per capita income at current prices. Thus, the vast majority of the unorganised sector incomes lie below the taxable limit, whether they are reported or not. Further as mentioned above (Section 7b), the unorganised sector is largely exempted from GST.

Thus, this sector is mostly outside the direct and indirect tax net. A rise in the tax collection reflects the growth of the organised sector, and not the economy as a whole.

As argued above, the Government’s attempt to formalise this sector has only damaged it, and that hurts the rural economy and agriculture, which are the largest employers. Agriculture produces the basics of life which everyone requires. So, a large part of demand for agricultural produce comes from the unorganised sector itself. As the incomes in the unorganised sector decline, demand for agricultural produce falls. That is reflected in malnourishment and under-nourishment and high stocks of foodgrains. This leads to lower prices of agricultural produce and lower incomes for the farmers, workers and rural producers. In a vicious cycle, demand and incomes across the unorganised sectors decline (See Kumar, 2022a).

Since the GDP data does not capture the decline in these incomes, the government is in denial about the deteriorating economic situation. Consequently, policy makers do not feel the need to help the unorganised sectors.

So, the unorganised sector is invisiblised both in data and in policy.

8. Macro Variables Impacted by GDP Errors

GDP data are used to estimate other macroeconomic variables, such as consumption and investment. So errors in one lead to errors in the other. The unorganised sector mostly produces consumption goods, such as food and items of day to day consumption, especially, for the marginalised sections. Production of capital goods is largely in the organised sector. The over-estimation of GDP contribution of the unorganised sector means that consumption goods production is over-estimated. (Estimation of investment would not be impacted by this factor, since both GDP and consumption are over-estimated by the same amount.)

Since the unorganised sector employs 94 per cent of the workforce, its decline causes growing under-employment, disguised unemployment and workers dropping out of labour force. So, while more people seek work in this sector, their income is over-estimated and poverty is more than depicted. Kumar (2022a) estimates that in 2021-22, 280 million workers did not have proper work.

Finally, growth in the organised sectors at the expense of the unorganised sector accentuates disparities. This inequality is not just between capital and labour but also between the owners of big business on the one hand and the owners of small and micro businesses. In per capita income terms, the economy is at 138th position in the world, but given the rising inequality, even this low average does not reflect the actual living standard of the marginalised.

Impact on Poverty Estimation

The problems in employment pointed to above lead to fewer members of the household earning incomes, and that causes increase in family poverty. Inflation adds to the woes of the poor by reducing the purchasing power of their already low wages. This leads to further decrease in demand which results in economic slowdown..

Even if the unorganised sector incomes stagnate, poverty cannot be declining. But, the Government claims a reduction in ‘multi-dimensional poverty’ between 2015-16 and 2019-21 on the basis of data from the National Health and Family Surveys (NHFS). Kumar (2023b) points out this cannot be correct, given that the terminal year is the pandemic year, 2020, when most children were out of school; there were many additional deaths and illnesses and for a vast majority of citizens; and the standard of living fell as their incomes declined.

In brief, given that the level of income, consumption and employment in the unorganised sector is less than depicted in the official data, poverty has to be greater than what is officially stated.

9. Black Economy and Marginalisation

Digitisation was supposed to curb illegality by making systems foolproof. Instead, new kinds of illegality have surfaced while the old forms of illegality and fraud continue. In India, the black economy is concentrated in the hands of the top 3 per cent of earners, who benefit from it at the expense of the 97 per cent (Kumar, 1999 and Kumar, 2017). Thus, income distribution is much more skewed than revealed in the white economy data. The black economy has an impact on a number of aspects of the macroeconomy – the level of inflation, the productivity of investment, the availability of Government resources for welfare schemes, and the extent to which welfare schemes actually reach targeted beneficiaries. Finally, it affects the social and political system itself.

Kumar (1999) points out that the solution to this problem is not economic or technological. That is why the hundreds of economic and technological measures tried over the last 75 years have not been able to check the growth of the black economy. Even digitisation has not yielded results. For instance, measures undertaken like, demat accounts, Aadhaar, and PAN have been circumvented in connivance with those in charge of the schemes. (Kumar, 2017). But the Government has resisted moves to bring its top functionaries under the purview of RTI, and to strengthen the whistle blowers’ protection.

Black incomes are generated largely by high income earners who belong mostly to the organised sector. The organised sector is considerably digitised, but that has not stopped it from generating black incomes via under- and over-invoicing. (Firms routinely understate or overstate the price of a sale or a purchase in order to transfer funds illicitly. This is done in particular with exports and imports. However, the digital record shows only a legitimate transaction.) Digitisation by itself has not checked black income generation.

If the black economy had been dented due to the steps undertaken by the government in the last 9 years, the direct tax/GDP ratio should have risen substantially. (Kumar, 2023d) shows that the ratio has continued to hover between 5.75 and 6.1 per cent, indicating that the black economy in India has not been dented.

10. Growing Inequality and Demand Shortage

Digitalisation has resulted in the strengthening of Capital against Labour. Capital has become highly mobile since the 1980s, and that enables it to extract concessions from national and sub-national governments, such as to dilute labour laws. The result has been a decline in the wage share in value of output of the corporate sector (Kumar, 2007 and Goldar, 2013).

Inequality increases as the organised sector grows at the expense of the unorganised sector. This inequality is not just between Capital and Labour, but also between the owners of big business on the one hand and the owners of small and micro businesses. Further, multinational capital’s share in the financial markets and in ownership of Indian companies has grown over time, and that also aggravates inequality.

These varying kinds of inequality have major macroeconomic consequences. Importantly, a shortage of demand persists, which slows down growth. This was evident in the pre-pandemic period of the last quarter of 2017-18 to the last quarter of 2019-20. For eight consecutive quarters the official rate of growth dropped from 8 per cent to 3.1per cent. The result was that, according to the RBI, capacity utilisation in industry hovered at about 73 per cent. These are figures pertaining only to the corporate sector. The slowdown occurred in spite of the huge concession in 2019 in corporation tax, amounting to Rs.1.6 lakh crore in the first year itself.

This concession reflects the Government’s bias. It seeks to tackle inadequate demand by offering more concessions to businesses. What was required was more incomes in the hands of the marginalised, and not more concessions to Capital. It makes it obvious that the Indian State is working against the interest of its citizens, most of whom work in the unorganised sector.

11. Conclusion

Digitalisation and formalisation are projected by the Government as a solution to the Indian economy’s problems, such as tackling the black economy and improving tax collection. Towards this end, the Government has taken various steps such as demonetisation, GST, Direct Benefit Transfer (DBT) and Aadhaar. While the goals set for these steps have not been achieved, new problems have emerged, since the unorganised sector has been adversely hit.

It is pointed out that the non-agriculture unorganised sector is not independently estimated in the GDP and is proxied by the growing organised sector. Demonetisation, GST and lockdown administered shocks to the economy and rendered invalid the method of estimating the contribution of the unorganised sector to the GDP. The shocks led to a disproportionately large adverse impact on this sector compared to the organised sector.

Further, while the organised sector recovered, the unorganised sector could not do so due to these repeated shocks. Thus, using the organised sector as a proxy for estimating the unorganised sector is incorrect and leads to an overestimation of GDP and other variables such as consumption. The result is an underestimation of inequality and poverty in India.

It is pointed out that the economic units in the unorganised sector are too small to get formalised, even if they start transacting through banks and digital mode. So digitisation has further damaged this sector without formalising it. This has proved to be a costly mistake, since demand has been shifting from the unorganised to the organised sector. This is like colonisation. Given that the organised sector is more capital intensive than the unorganised sector, the demand shift has resulted in decrease in employment generation, under-employment, disguised unemployment and persistence of poverty. It has resulted in greater inequality and shortage of demand which has led to the economy slowing down.

The Government’s promotion of digitalisation represents its policy bias in favor of the organised sector. The multinational corporations (MNCs) prefer a more digitised economy since it is advantageous for them.

Since the unorganised sector is not independently estimated, it is invisiblised in data. It enables the Government to claim that Indian economy is the fastest growing large economy and nothing is wrong with it. So no special steps are required to help the declining unorganised sector. Thereby it gets invisiblised in policy also.

References:

1 . Bhalla, S, (2009) `Definitional and Statistical Issues Relating to Workers in Informal Employment’. Working Paper No.3 of National Commission for Enterprises in the Unorganised Sector. January.

2. Bhowmick, C., Goel, S., Das S. and Gautam, (2022) ‘A Composite Coincident Index for Unorganised Sector Activity in India’. Mimeo. RBI Bulletin, December.

3. Goldar, B. (2013), ‘Wages and wage share in India during the post-reform period’. Indian Journal of Labour Economics. 56(1):75-94. January.

4. Government of India, Ministry of Labour & Employment, (2007) Report of the National Commission for Enterprises in the Unorganised Sector (NCEUS). Chairperson: Arjun Sengupta.

5. Government of India, Ministry of Labour & Employment, (2008) Contribution of the Unorganised Sector to GDP: Report of the Sub-Committee of a NCEUS Task Force. Chairperson: K P Kannan.

6. Government of India, Ministry of Statistics and Programme Implementation, National Sample Survey Office, (2017a) Key Indicators of Unincorporated Non-Agricultural Enterprises (Excluding Construction) in India. NSS 73rd Round. (July 2015 – June 2016).

7. Government of India, (2017b) Methodology of Compiling Quarterly GDP Estimates. July.

8. Government of India, Ministry of Micro, Small & Medium Enterprises, (2023) Contribution of MSMEs to the Country’s GDP. 11 December.

9. Kumar, A. (1999) The Black Economy in India.

10. ———— (2005) ‘India’s Black Economy: The Macroeconomic Implications’. South Asia: Journal of South Asian Studies. Vol. 28, No.2. August, pp. 249-263.

11. ———— (2007) ‘Macro Overview’. In: Alternative Economic Survey Group (Ed.), Pampering Corporates Pauperizing Masses, pp. 37 – 46.

12. ———– (2013) Indian Economy Since Independence: Persisting Colonial Disruption.

13. ———– (2017) Demonetization and Black Economy.

14. ———– (2018) Ground Scorching Tax.

15. ———– (2020) Indian Economy’s Greatest Crisis: Impact of the Coronavirus and the Road Ahead.

16. ———— (2022a) Report of the People’s Commission on Employment and Unemployment, set up by Desh Bachao Andolan. Mimeo. Chairperson: Arun Kumar. October.

17. ———— (2022b) “India’s Unorganised Sector Is Being Engulfed, Further Marginalised”, The Wire, November 18. https://thewire.in/economy/indias-unorganised-sector-is-being-engulfed-further-marginalised

18. ———— (2023a) “Three Notes of Caution as India Celebrates Its GDP Growth”. The Wire, June 2. https://thewire.in/economy/gdp-growth-2023-high-economy

19. ———— (2023b) “Is the Decline in Multi-dimensional Poverty in India Real?”. The Leaflet, August 6. https://theleaflet.in/is-the-decline-in-multidimensional-poverty-in-india-real/

20. ———— (2023c) “GDP Growth: Official Stance and Reality”. The Leaflet, October 6. https://theleaflet.in/gdp-growth-the-gap-between-reality-and-rhetoric/

21. ———— (2023d) “Income Tax Data Reveals That Increase in Compliance Is Marginal”. The Wire, November 24. https://thewire.in/economy/income-tax-data-reveals-that-increase-in-compliance-is-marginal

22. Niti Aayog, (2024) “Multidimensional Poverty in India since 2005-06: A Discussion Paper”, January 15.

23. Oxfam. (2023), “Survival of the Richest: The India Story”. https://www.oxfamindia.org/knowledgehub/workingpaper/survival-richest-india-story . Accessed January 17, 2023.

24. Williamson, J. (1989) “What Washington Means by Policy Reform”. In Williamson, J (ed.): Latin American Readjustment: How Much has Happened? Institute for International Economics, Washington.

More In This Issue

Digitalisation in India: The Class Agenda [Part II]
Digitalisation in India: The Class Agenda [Part II]

The decade of ‘peak digitalisation’ has witnessed depressed consumption, stalled investment, retrogression in the pattern of employment, and falling real wages. Meanwhile the digital economy has grown as an enclave, increasingly disconnected from the rest of the economy.

Digitalisation in India: The Class Agenda [Part I]
Digitalisation in India: The Class Agenda [Part I]

The champions of digitalisation claim that “India is upgrading – from an offline, cash, informal, low productivity economy to an online, cashless, formal, high productivity economy.” In fact, the manner in which digitalisation is being imposed on various sectors of India’s predominantly informal economy does not bring about true formalisation or raise the productivity of the vast majority of working people; rather, it serves to enrich the corporate sector, including global corporations, at the expense of that vast majority.

The Digitalisation Onslaught: Precarity and Exclusion
The Digitalisation Onslaught: Precarity and Exclusion

The dominant discourse is that ‘digital’ provides for greater efficiencies, opportunities and ‘democratisation’. However, the period of increasing digitisation in India has also been a period of growing poverty, and growing disjunction between the Growth Domestic Product (GDP) and employment. ‘Digitalisation’ is continuously generating exclusion for vast numbers: persons without smartphones, or without digital skills, or living in areas where digital infrastructure is poor; persons unable to authenticate using Aadhaar, for various reasons; workers replaced by automation, robots and artificial intelligence; workers trapped in precarious ‘gig’ employment, without security or rights; and so on. Those who are left out of vikaas (development) are no longer citizens with entitlements and rights, but mere labharthis waiting for doles to be handed out to them at the whims of the political class. It remains to be seen what deeper crises unfold now and what kind of social resistance arises to confront this onslaught.

Automating Exclusions: How Digitalisation Can Lead to Exclusions in Welfare Programmes
Automating Exclusions: How Digitalisation Can Lead to Exclusions in Welfare Programmes

Official claims that digitalisation will eliminate fraud, remove unwanted intermediaries, and seamlessly and rapidly transfer funds to the intended beneficiaries are not borne out in practice. Instead the digitalisation drive has automated exclusions, increased opacity for NREGA workers and other beneficiaries, lengthened the ‘last mile’, and placed workers at the mercy of Aadhaar. Further, introducing more digital systems cannot solve the core problem of insufficient funds, which is a political decision.

Making Sense of the Present Moment of ‘Onlinisation’ of Teaching
Making Sense of the Present Moment of ‘Onlinisation’ of Teaching

If education is more than merely offering ‘content’, online education is very far from a serious teacher’s idea of reasonable education. Among other things, it ignores the role of the peer group in collective learning; the role of social diversity in learning; the importance of providing students equal access to institutional resources; the scope for students to escape socio-political fetters and the disadvantages of their ‘homes’ by physically entering a place of learning; and the importance of beyond-classroom learning in the collective life of a physical institution. The actual results of online learning have been dismal. Yet, instead of training more teachers, lowering the costs of higher education and widening its reach, the emphasis is on making education a commercial commodity.

Digitalisation of Education: A Dystopian Solution for a Dismal Reality
Digitalisation of Education: A Dystopian Solution for a Dismal Reality

After almost eight decades since independence, the state of India’s school education remains in complete disarray. Though a significant number of children of school-going age have been herded into schools, the learning levels remain dismal in spite of very low bars set to assess them. In this situation, there is a wholesale push for edtech by the cartel of Capital and ‘non-profits’ (funded by Capital), with the State providing a massive boost for the commercialisation and privatisation of schools. While education will be a casualty, this policy promises savings for the State and profits for Capital.

The Toll-Booth City: Notes on ‘Smart’ Urbanism
The Toll-Booth City: Notes on ‘Smart’ Urbanism

The promotion of digital technology as an apolitical solution for urban problems is a class politics – of interests that drive global consultant firms, technology providers, big bureaucracy, and vendor networks. It seeks to simultaneously obscure the nature of urban problems as well as the social-class dimension of ‘smart’ urbanism. The Smart City Mission is a part of the toll-booth model of urbanisation: the outsourcing of traditional urban government functions to the hands of state-private corporate entities, the expropriation of public assets and the privatisation of public goods and services, and the creation and policing of exclusive networks and enclaves – in order to generate opportunities for rent extraction (tolls).

Digital Health and the National Digital Health Mission – Leveraging “Universal Health Care” for Technology and Capital?
Digital Health and the National Digital Health Mission – Leveraging “Universal Health Care” for Technology and Capital?

The ongoing inroads of digital technology into health through the National Digital Health Mission (NDHM) are the latest chapter in the now nearly hundred-year-old discourse on the role of technology in health, on what protects and improves public health. The history of public health and medicine shows that countries managed to improve the health of their populations, achieve health equity and universal health care (and not simply universal health coverage) without the most advanced technologies. NDHM fits into the ‘Gates approach’ to global health, leveraging ‘Universal Health Care’ in the interests of the makers and owners of (digital) technology and capital.

3